Robert MonkVersion 1.1
Responses in the Family to Industrialization and other Effects of
Capital Intensification in Europe 17801900
Whether situated in a rural or an urban setting, European households in the
century 17801900 adapted new strategies for coping with the rapid changes in
means to livelihood that were brought on by increasingly capital-intensive
technologies of production. As Louise Tilly has pointed out, the strategies of a
household intersect with a number of factors, such as "the economic and social
structures in which the household is located, ... and ... the processes of change which
these structures are undergoing"(Tilly, 1978; p. 3). More or less, depending on the
region, "social structures" could include responding strategies of social control initiated
by middle-class organizations and by the government, which increasingly served as
the agent of the middle class; traditions of leisure, courtship, and social values and
moral standards; the quality and availability of work relations of labor to capital, the
level of real wages, seasonality of wages, and differentials in wages along age and
gender lines. A study of family strategies provides unique insight into all these topics,
but I will treat only last one labor with any thoroughness.
For several reasons, patterns of behavior may be most visible as they manifest
themselves in the structure of households, but this does not mean that households
are necessarily the most important unit of decision making for the nineteenth-century
working class. Thus, before turning exclusively to aspects of family structure related to
family size (number of children), I will use a broad comparison of more general
strategies to argue that the relative importance of family strategy and individual
self-interest depends on the rate of change the strategy responds to as well as the
social group (child, man, woman, employed and unemployed) to which the individual
belongs.
The term 'family strategy' conveys a sense that households were somehow the
most important unit of response to changing circumstances. Some would argue
precisely this. Tilly writes:
The concept of family strategies works as a series of hypotheses about, as Pierre Bourdieu puts it,
"implicit principles", less rigid or articulated than decision rules, by which the household, not the
individual, not the society as a whole, acts as the unit of decision making. [Tilly, 1978; p. 3]
Family strategy may attain as the unit of decision making when social change is slow
enough to permit the traditions that structure family to change as fast as individual
interests. When change is fast, however, individual interests are more likely to conflict
with family strategy and more likely to be indulged in spite of it. In crisis circumstances,
individuals within the family order may act independently and in conflict with the needs
and demands of the family strategy. Family strategy must then adjust to changes in the
behavior of individuals, not the other way around. This is not to suggest that the
individual is the principle unit of decision making, only putting her divergent interests
into visible relief during times of crisis. Rather, in periods of stressful change old family
strategies become faulty and their limitations are revealed. Individuals seek
alternatives that are viable within the new order, and they tend to reproduce what they
can of the old strategy.
Others have suggested a unit of decision-making not smaller, but larger than
the family. In her analysis of poor-lists and other sources on Antwerp 1770-1860,
Catharina Lis concludes tentatively that "where Antwerp is concerned, the role of the
neighborhood as the organizing principle in the construction of relations of reciprocity
and solidarity ought to be accorded great importance"(Lis; p.158). Her strongest
evidence is negative family relations of reciprocity were grossly inadequate after
about 1840 or from literary sources, and, as she herself admits, "none of it is beyond
dispute." Rather than an emphasis on neighborhood networks as the organizing
principle of working-class social relations in Antwerp, I see evidence for a dialectical
process in which rapid change in economic conditions stimulates self-interested
individual responses that gradually accommodate one another in the form of a new
equilibrium family organization. During a period of rapid and stressful change, such
as Antwerp's in the first half of the Nineteenth Century, family strategy reflects the
various interests of its individual participants only after sufficient time has elapsed for
new patterns of individual behavior to accommodate one another.
For the period following 1820 generally considered a period of very rapid
industrial growth and even rising real wages there seems to be a trend of falling
wages for women, especially women beyond their late twenties. The older women Lis
studied in Antwerp, those in England that Rule considered at a very general (Rule; p.
178) level and Anderson more narrowly, and the women Tilly studied in Roubaix,
France all confronted at some time after 1820 a change in the structure of the job
market favouring men (and to some extent younger women) almost to their exclusion.
One explanation for this change in Preston seems appropriate in light of Lis'
analysis of the labor market in Antwerp. Anderson's study of Preston shows that male
factory workers (SEG VI) in the cotton industry worked there only in the early phase of
a complex work-cycle (Anderson, 1971; pp. 26-8). Upon leaving the factory, the
majority became labourers, some higher factory workers, and a few tradesmen. Even
though Preston was very different from Antwerp (its textiles industry did not collapse,
for instance), the structure of work opportunities for women seems to be similar.
Women were forced to leave the factories at a young age (Anderson, 1971; pp. 71-3).
In Antwerp, employment, particularly for older women, was virtually eliminated with the
collapse of the textiles industry. Antwerp's emergence as an important port-town
provided labor for strong, male, casual laborers, but not women (Lis; pp. 36-77). Like
the women of Antwerp, the women of Preston had few alternatives open to them after
an initial phase in the factories (where half of all working women were employed).
Tilly notes the impact on family strategy of this type of urban industrial setting, in
which there was structural unemployment for women :
In Roubaix in 1872, as in Preston, Lancashire, (1851) as described by Michael Anderson,
there was an apparently successful family effort to keep children in the household and working for
the family wage fund. AsAnderson suggests, and as our comparison of Roubaix with the
fragmentary evidence for the Avesnes weavers corroborates, parents and children lived together
longer in the textile city than in agricultural or weaving villages. [Tilly, 1978; pp. 18-19]
Tilly notes two factors influencing such co-habitation that are similar both to the factors
Anderson defines in his study of Preson (Anderson, 1971; p. 141) and to those Lis
identified in her study of Antwerp. These are short supply of housing, and the services
with which wives, employed and unemployed, attracted even the high wage-earning
members of the younger generation. Anderson's analysis adds the advantage of
sharing family furniture, where a young couple would have had little in the way of
savings with which to buy their own. It also suggests that expensive housing was not a
necessary constraint in cases where young couples sought co-habitation with older
family; the opportunity to save rent may have been enough for them. The universality
of most of these factors indicates the strong possibility that this strategy of co-habitation
may have been quite widespread in industrial towns, where housing was a relatively
significant factor in household budgets.
Tilly also notes that "Wider kin networks facilitated migration and kin or
neighborhood networks of women helped people find jobs or gave aid in times of
unemployment or sickness"(Tilly, 1978; p. 19). Such a close parallel to the networks
whose existence Lis tries to establish warrants more attention. Were neighborhood
relief-networks important in all three cities (Preston, Roubaix, Antwerp)? If so, did the
large proportion of inmigrants in these cities tend to intensify neighborhood networks
where they would not normally be effective? Unfortunately, I cannot address these
questions here.
That the responding strategies used by families of such far-flung cities were
similar adds needed weight and some qualification to Tilly's assertion that the
objective of working-class family strategies was "to promote nuclear family survival
over a cycle of family expansion and contraction, from marriage of the couple, through
child bearing, child departures, return to the solitary couple, and death of its
members"(Tilly, 1978; p. 5). Her own examples, as well as examples from Preston
and Antwerp, suggest family survival was indeed the objective of family strategies, but
that the working classes were not particularly concerned about preserving the nuclear
structure of their families (1). That families took many different forms over time and
space rather than prefering a nuclear structure is evidence that they were responding
to the interests of their constituent individuals to some extent.
I have already reviewed Tilly's own analysis of Roubaix, which contradicts her
assertion that the objective of family strategy implied a stage in which a solitary couple
played a part . In her analysis of marriage statistics and other indicators of household
structure in Antwerp, Lis describes a family strategy that explains patterns both in
Antwerp after the 1820s, and in Roubaix in the last quarter of the Nineteenth Century.
Lis establishes that there was increasingly a shortage of working class housing within
the city of Antwerp (Lis; Part III). At the same time, as housing costs were rising
dramatically, employment for women collapsed along with Antwerp's textile industries,
dropping from a rate of some 80% in 1780 to only 55% employed by the mid-
Nineteenth Century (Lis; p. 37). At the marginal wage-rates available to Antwerp
workers, living as a solitary couple would have been feasible and even preferable
before the Nineteenth Century, but as the cost of living-space rose and the
earnings-contribution that could be expected from women fell, bare survival would
require alterations in family strategy.
The statistics Lis looks at suggest a lag-time between changes in the social
topography and adequate adjustments at the level of household. During this lag-time,
individual self-interest prevailed. Lis states the males' economic perspective well:
Given that the economic transformation of Antwerp entailed structural unemployment for a
growing number of women and nearly all young children, and that the real wages [calculated in
terms of rye-bread] of those who could still get a job fell sharply, it seems probable that more and
more male workers would have thought twice before marrying.
and her statistics bear this out:
Percentage of unmarried citzens over 20 in Antwerp, categorized by sex, 17961856
Females Males
1796 44.4 32.3
1830 44.9 38.0
1846 44.1 41.7
1856 41.2 43.0
[pp. 140-1]
Growth in the percentage of bachelors was even greater for predominantly proletarian
sectors of the city (p. 141). The initial response to structural changes in employment
opportunity involved at least a strong component of individual self-preservation. Men
were not as likely to accept fatherhood of their children, since this would mean a
substantial fall in living-standard. Women increasingly found themselves pregnant
and unmarried. Since poor-relief was made available only to mothers of legitimate
children, these women increasingly abandoned their babies to the foundling hospital.
In those cases where men took responsibility for their children, they did so increasingly
through arrangements of unmarried co-habitation in order to avoid the costs of
marriage.
As I have already hinted, this change in marriage practices had repercussions
in reproduction statistics, and it is on the basis of these that Lis suggests the delayed
response of household strategy to changing social conditions. The ratio of foundlings
to total births grew, but only through the 1830s, after which it fell off considerably.
While illigitimate births had been on the rise through the last half of the Eighteenth
Century, the pace accelerated after 1780; but, like the foundling ratio, it seems to have
peaked around 1840. According to Lis' interpretation, generations that grew up after
1830 could not have avoided recognizing the severe challenge present in Antwerp's
state of poverty. More importantly, perhaps, they would have seen the effects of sexual
practices that were unsuited to the new condition of structural unemployment for
women. By the 1840s, couples, and particularly women, had realized that pregnancy
out of wedlock was no longer a virtual assurance of eventual marriage. If men did not
always abandon pregnant women outright, couples were finding marriage more and
more often a financial impossibility (Lis; p. 146).
After an initial period in which self-interest predominated, a new family strategy
emerged. Unmarried children and young couples (married and unmarried) lived more
often with their parents, widows were more likely to live with kin, especially a married
child, and couples who had been parents for less than six years were less likely to be
married (Lis; pp. 144-6). These strategies were suited to the circumstances. The cost
of housing was increasingly prohibitive. Living in over-stuffed space was preferable to
spending most of the family earnings on shelter and having not enough to eat. Due to
structural unemployment, widows, despite modest help from the Charity Bureau, could
not survive alone unless prepared to subject themselves to the prison-like conditions
of the poor-house (Lis; p. 155). Though they were probably an increasing burden to
the young couples who took them in, these widows could offer domestic services such
as house-keeping and child-care to those couples fortunate enough to have dual
incomes. Child-care would have been particularly helpful between 1800 and 1840,
when child employment decreased dramatically (45% in 1827 down to 11.5% in
1855)(Lis; p. 38), and schooling had not yet become common. Toward the end of this
period, however, both real wages for men and employment for young women
declined. As the the couples' earnings-surplus shrank, so did their preference for the
parents' domestic services. Not surprisingly, the number of widows seeking poor-relief
increased considerably after 1840 (Lis; pp. 152-4). In Antwerp during the first half of
the Nineteenth Century, individual self-interest was gradually fixed into appropriate
family strategies as different groups (men and women; young and old) adjusted to one
another's initially self-centered strategies for survival. The extreme poverty of Antwerp
put unusual and continuing pressure on its poor throughout the Nineteenth Century,
making any equilibrium reached in this way merely a tentative one.
(1)Tilly claimed that the objective of family strategies was "to promote nuclear
family survival over a cycle of family expansion and contraction" that ended with a
"solitary couple." Yet the reality of family strategies in the urban settings of Roubaix
and Antwerp was that they varied from the nuclear norm when it was convenient to do
so. The flexibility of working class household structure in these two cases suggests
that perhaps 'family strategy' is a useful concept mostly because individuals
(particularly high wage-earning young males) saw family arrangements as the means
to the highest standard of living. Admittedly, other factors were probably also at work,
such as a sense of responsibility to mothers, whose potential to contribute in a nuclear
family's household economy was decreasing after 1820. As Lis demonstrates,
however, the economic advantages of multi-generational co-habitation in a highly
pressurized housing market made it the best, if not the only choice, even for the most
independent groups (young men) of the working class. Young men and young
couples moved in with parents because they could save on housing costs, while the
value of the older mother's house-keeping and child-care time was increased, as it
served more people. Family strategy in Antwerp and Roubaix moved away from its
older, nuclear structure under the pressure of social change.
There was an important difference between the changes in Antwerp and those
in Roubaix. In Roubaix, changes in household structure were slower and more lasting
than in Antwerp. The 'stem' family that resulted in Roubaix was maintained through
the end of Tilly's study in 1914, whereas in Antwerp, in a span of a hundred years a
typical widow went from being capable of self-sufficiency, through dependence on
reciprocal relations with kin, to dependence on institutionalized public support. Older
couples who were not self-sufficient were also increasingly likely to be abandoned by
their children.
Judging from this comparison, family strategy can be understood best as an
equilibrium between the diverse interests of the many social positions that constitute
the family. These would include employed and unemployed children, employed and
unemployed men and women, mothers caring for infants, and employed and
unemployed elders both married and widowed. The individualist basis of the family
strategies shaped by these interests becomes apparent only under pressure from the
very rapid change wrought by capital-intensification such as that which took place in
Antwerp between 1770 and 1860. In Antwerp, for the period Lis studied, change was
too fast for any viable equilibrium family strategy to become established.
Neighborhood networks may have taken up the slack, but evidence for this is slim.
More clear is the extent of the dire poverty that Antwerp's working class was victim to
and the degree to which individual self-interest determined resulting strategies for
survival.
In discussing the role of family strategy in working-class lives I have said little
about how it affected children, and what role they played in household economies.
Why did couples bring children into the marginal existence that was the norm for so
many European families in the Nineteenth Century? Why did they limit their families to
three or four children in Roubaix, four or six in Preston, two or three in Antwerp, and
not at all in the neighborhood of Avesnes-les-Aubert where Mémé, the subject of Tilly's
case study, was born? Habit, conditioning, and direct social pressure must have
played some role in directing couples to produce children, just as they do today. Birth
control devices, if available, were not as effective then as they are now. Finally, even if
they were not always helpful or necessary in the early stages of a marriage, productive
children were very important to couples and the widowed in their old age as a source
of support. Even in regions where the poor-laws provided adequate assistance for the
helpless, accepting bureaucratic aid was considered shameful and was often made
extremely unpleasant (Lis; Chapter 13).
Regional differences in family size are largely attributable to differing economic
circumstances, though, as with the decision to have children in the first place, habit
and conditioning must have had some effect on the numbers produced. A comparison
between strategies employed by framework knitters in Shepshed, Leicestershire and
those of the Camberlot hand-loom weavers of Avesnes-les-Aubert gives an idea of
how circumstances can affect family size. In David Levine's analysis, the
proto-industrialist framework knitters of Shepshed faced the dual spectres of
over-population on one hand, and the precariousness of a household economy based
on a single wage-earner, on the other. The response was emmigration (arguably an
aspect of family strategy, but not one I will discuss), co-habitation of the kind already
described, and high fertility through earlier marriage (Levine; pp. 155-6).
In 1815, framework knitting was still largely a household production, and one
carried out most efficiently by several people. Young couples compressed their
reproductive stage into the first years of their marriage, when the added cost of
non-producing children was offset by the benefits of co-habitation. High infant
mortality was met with high fertility as the means of ensuring the help of additional
workers by the time the couple established its own household. Furthermore, insofar as
children were considered a source of welfare in old age (Levine claims they were), a
single child was little assurance until it was beyond five years of age (Levine; p. 157).
Since children were born about two years apart, even a risky compromise meant
producing two or three children, and though women "deliberately restricted their
fertility"(Levine; p. 155) in the later years of marriage, birth control has never been
perfect. Hoping to guarantee their welfare in old age and to obtain the productive
capacity that was necessary for an independent household, young, co-habiting
Shepshed families produced many children early on, despite growing population
pressure.
Though the hand-loom weavers in Tilly's study of Avesnes engaged in a similar
proto-industry, and though, like the framework knitters of Shepshed, Avesnes weavers
responded to competition from factory production by emmigration, the family-size was
considerably larger in Avesnes, and there was no corresponding period of
co-habitation for couples. Whereas Shepshed families averaged four or five children,
the typical number in Mémé's neighborhood generally was ten or more (Tilly, 1978; p.
11). There are differences between the two regions which may explain these differing
strategies. Avesnes weavers managed to supplement their collapsing cottage industry
with seasonal agricultural work in Normandy, some 100 miles distant (Tilly, 1978; p.
6). From the perspective of the single household economy, agricultural work provided
labor for as many children as a couple could produce. Tilly calls the Camberlot
weavers' excedingly long seasonal migration one of "a rather drastic series of
expediencies" by which they were able to prolong the domestic weaving industry until
World War I (Tilly, 1978; p. 6). As I will argue shortly, their unusually large families
may have been a part of this attempt to preserve an old mode of production.
The absence of nearby kin may have been a decisive factor in non
co-habitation. Mémé relates how her parents, the Gardez, embarked on the
high-fertility strategy, but without the support of co-habitation or kin. Tilly summarizes:
In 1871, the Gardez were a young couple with three children under five. Pierre was called to
serve in the Franco-Prussian War, and a tragic drama ensued. Marie Catharine, pregnant with her
fourth child, was not able to weave enough to support herself and three little children. The infant
she gave to a neighbor to mind died due to the baby sitter's carelessness. The two girls died of
sickness. When he heard the news of his children's deaths, Gardez ran away from his regiment
and returned home to weave. ... The couple's division of labor required the husband's labor,
and wages, to support his wife in her child bearing years when there were no children old enough
to work. [Tilly, 1978; pp. 12-13]
Clearly, co-habitation would have benefited the Gardez. Whether they would have
done it, given the chance, is impossible to tell.
They did send their children into service with other families during the winters,
when they were at work on the looms. Beyond the fifth child, additional working
children were of little help at home during the winter, since only four or five could work
efficiently at the looms (Tilly, 1978; p. 15). Older children were replaced by younger,
and they went into service for other families and/or married young at around
eighteen for Mémé and her eleven sisters.
Without the yearly migration to the sugar-beet fields of Normandy, such large
families would have made little economic sense. In the summers, when their housing
and food was provided by their commercial agricultural employer, the Gardez enjoyed
the benefits of many wage-earners without the costs of supporting them. They used
the surplus from this summer employment to pay their debt to their Avesnes baker,
which accumulated every winter due to the insufficiency of income from the winter
weaving (Tilly, 1978; p. 13). In the winter, they had the optimum labor input for their
four-loom domestic weaving operation. The Gardez' many children enabled the family
to continue its domestic weaving by supplying labor when it was needed and
becoming scarce when it was not.
High fertility must have been of benefit to the community, as well. If, as with the
framework knitting Levine describes, optimal efficiency on the hand-loom was reached
only with two or more labourers, there would presumably have been households that
could benefit from taking in servants. The added efficiency and increased total
production would help to bring the parents of a young child through the precarious
period of low producion-consumption ratios that Mémé's parents fell victim to. If
domestic weaving was to survive as long as it did in Avesnes, the high fertility
exemplified by the Gardez family was a necessary strategy.
While the circumstances of the framework knitters and the hand-loom weavers
were similar a failing market for the products of cottage industry, emmigration,
young marriage, high fertility the seasonal migration that the weavers undertook,
and their lack of nearby kin must have been contributing factors in the differences
family size and co-habitation between the two resulting family strategies. Would
seasonal agricultural work have been a sufficient supplement to declining domestic
industry of the Camberlot weavers without the strategy of very large families? Would
Shepshed framework knitters have persisted as long as they did without
co-habitation? That I can ask these questions indicates at least the potential
importance of family strategies in the larger economic picture.
The interests of the individual do not seem to have played much of a role in
these two examples of rural working-class economies. Part of the reason for this must
be that I largely ignored the decision-making of adults for themselves. A discussion of
strategies of family size necessarily begins with the assumption that there is a couple
strategizing, so questions of whether and when to marry recede in importance.
Anderson offers another reason. Based on evidence from his study of Preston workers
as well as the rural communities from which they immigrated, he claims that the
presence of alternative life-styles played a major role in the willingness of more
capable individuals to repudiate their families (Anderson, Chapter 7). In rural
proto-industrial towns, there would have been little alternative to the family production
unit. To some extent, young, capable people did indeed take advantage of the one
alternative that was available emigration to urban industrial centers.
Family strategy played an important role in working class responses to social
change. In the cities of Antwerp, Preston, and Roubaix, family structure responded to
high housing costs and decreasing employment for women by shifting from the
nuclear household to one that involved some kind of co-habitation. In the struggling
proto-industrial economies of Shepshed and Avesnes-les-Aubert, families tried to
keep domestic production alive by high fertility combined with either co-habitation or
supplemental agricultural work. Whether in an urban or an agricultural setting, family
strategy could not maintain hegemony in decision making. While the comparatively
many alternatives open to workers in an urban economy dominated by factory- or
other non-domestic employment made family strategies more precarious in the cities,
emigration offered rural youth engaged in domestic production at least one opportunity
for escaping the family-oriented strategies of their parents.
Bibliography
Lis, Catharina, Social Change and the Labouring Poor: Antwerp 1770-1860
published in New Haven, CT, 1986, by Yale University Press.
Rule, John, The Labouring Classes in Early Industrial England 1750-1850
published in London, 1986, by Longman Group Limited
Tilly, Louise, Women and Family Strategies in French Proletarian Families
4th in the series "Michigan Occasional Papers in Women's Studies"
published in Ann Arbor, 1978, by the Women's Studies Program, University of
Michigan
Anderson, Michael, Family Structure in Nineteenth Century Lancashire
published in Cambridge, 1971, by Cambridge University Press
Levine, David, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Popular
History
published in New York, 1987, by Cambridge University Press
Loose Ends...
Especially in England, historians have had to contend with a mass of
contemporary literature claiming that working-class parents exploited their children in
order to increase their own leisure-time. While the odd drunken father probably did
just that, such literature has been dismissed by the majority of historians as grossly
misleading. Statements of the parents themselves indicate that they sent children to
work in a factory only as a last resort, and the figures in Anderson's study suggest the
same:
[I]n the large proportion of the cases where young children were employed, it is clear that they
were sent to work because the family was so poor that their earnings were absolutely essential if
the family was to continue to function at all as an effective unit. [Anderson, 1971; p. 75]
If couples produced children so as to ensure the presence of kinship support in
their old age, they may have produced many children in order to offer the later ones an
opportunity to advance their station. The nine children born before Mémé were
capable of creating enough surplus to allow her a few years in school before joining
them at the looms and in the fields. In Anderson's study, "A spinner sent his first four
children into the mill before they were ten, but the fifth he kept out of the factory until
the age of 12 or 13, 'because our circumstances were better'"(Anderson, 1971; pp.
76-7).
The ambiguous intersection between individual interests and family strategy
can be seen clearly in the roles that women play in Tilly's study of Roubaix and
Avesnes-les-Aubert in France. In her words, Roubaix "mothers bore the costs of their
children's and their husband's leisure and of whatever saving family, husband and
children did"(Tilly, 1978; p. 23). Perhaps women were more likely to behave
according to the needs of family strategy than men. Whether by choice or necessity,
women served family interests at their own expense.
Such a re-conceptualization of family strategy does not render the concept
meaningless, even when considering periods of rapid change when it would seem to
be least effective. Unless we are prepared to believe that people in past centuries
conceived of families as merely practical, economic associations and not also as the
locus of affective relationships, part of every individual's interest included membership
in some kind of family . People generally wanted family, so their approach to the
problem of living would include some component of family strategy: how to best live in
conjunction with one or more others.